Monday, November 30, 2009

The Advisor Weblog

The Advisor Weblog


Hourly perspective for U.S. session

Posted: 30 Nov 2009 06:21 AM PST

Usd/Jpy technical view

Posted: 30 Nov 2009 05:43 AM PST

After hitting an almost 15 years low, pair has closed Friday with quite a reversal candle formation, yet under 87.00 area, meaning bearish trend is not over in the term. 4 Hours charts indicators for today seems slightly bullish, yet looking at past week downside rally Fibo, we found that pair has been capped in between levels: 50% retracement comes also at the 87.00 zone, first resistance to consider from current level, followed by the 87.40 area, and above, 87.80. Supports for next hours are located at 86.40, 86.10 and today’s low, also 23.6% retracement at the 85.80 area.

 


Best pair to trade now: EUR/USD

Posted: 30 Nov 2009 05:12 AM PST

Eur/Usd for today

Posted: 30 Nov 2009 04:11 AM PST

Eur/Usd is losing part of the upside momentum gained in Asian session, and now test the 20 SMA in this 4 hours charts, that should act as dynamic support, as we are also around the 1.5020 area, that has capped the upside for long before pair reached a fresh yearly high close to 1.5100. Pair remains slightly bullish as long as above this 1.5000/20 support area, with next resistances coming at 1.5060 and the 1.5085/95 area. Clear break above, should send the pair to the 1.5160 level, 76.4% retracement of the monthly fall 1.6038/1.2330. To the downside, today’s low around 1.4970 seems to be the key support level to watch: break under should send the pair to test the 1.4930 area, and under 1.4880/1.4900.  As usual, stocks and gold will be leading the pair movements.

 


Majors’ sentiment for today

Posted: 30 Nov 2009 03:15 AM PST

Here is majors’ sentiment for today:

Eur/Usd: Slightly Bullish

Gbp/Usd: Bearish

Usd/Chf: Slightly Bearish

Usd/Jpy: Bearish

Eur/Gbp: Bullish


Starting the day

Posted: 30 Nov 2009 02:57 AM PST

Hi everyone, and welcome back! With a nice recovery in Asian indexes, dollar lost ground since past Sunday opening, rally that halted in Europe as European markets opened to the downside: fears regarding Dubai World bad debt remains and Euro and Pound gave up part of the wined ground. Gold remains unchanged just above $ 1170/oz.

Japanese Yen remains strong while Japan Prime Minister Hatomaya talk about act in respond to rising yen, still  remaining just talking but to consider a bit more seriously. Not a law, but remember Japan usually do this movements on weekends. Anyway, let’s start with the technicals for today. Here is the link for today's calendar:  

http://www.fxstreet.com/fundamental/economic-calendar/

Have a great day!


Romer's Growth Theory


It is generally presumed that Paul Romer will win a Nobel prize for his 'endogenous growth theory', so I was intrigued when Kling and Schultz interviewed him in their new book From Poverty to Prosperity. As mentioned yesterday, the book hits on a lot of issues I find interesting, not so much as providing a novel big idea, but noting a lot of outstanding puzzles and how the non-Left Establishment thinks about them.

Growth Theory is about long term economic growth, abstracting from business cycles. Given the power of compounding, and the ephemeral and intractible nature of business cycles, it is rather a shame for most economists to focus on recessions because over they don't matter too much over time. Sure, the East Germany had fewer recessions than West Germany, but over a couple generations, West Germany had 3 times the living standard. Wisdom is primarily prioritizing tasks according to importance and solubility.

Robert Solow started growith theory in the 1950s, and it basically broke the macroeconomy into three drivers: capital, labor, and productivity. It did not explain productivity, but did highlight that this factor seemed to be what really mattered, so no longer could one say, Tanzania needed more 'capital', because after you apply the model econometrically the problem is not capital or labor, but their productivity. Solow's growth model does not tell us how things work, but it did dismiss a popular incorrect idea, no small feat.

Romer highlights the fact that great economists, according to economists, are those that create great models. These models usually merely formalize existing intuition, as the Welfare Theorems of Arrow and Debreu really just proved the 'Invisible Hand' using set theory (ie, that a competitive equilibrium is Pareto Optimal, and that a Pareto Optimal Equilibrium is a competitive equilibrium). Or consider the Lucas Islands model, which modelled economic fluctuations as the result of unpredictable monetary growth an inflation. In the 1970's, this was a leading explanation of business cycles, but no longer. Nonetheless, the model remains in the canon because it is self-contained, has a lot of intuition, and inspires economists as to what they are trying to create. The hope is that one creates a mathematical model, like the Black-Scholes equation, that sheds light on new truths. Good models fit to existing phenomena should generalize in unexpected ways. Alas, this is rarely the case in economics, as the model usually remain parochial explanations of the economic fact that inspired it(eg, the Phillips Curve).

Romer's model is instigated by the fact that while there is convergence within various economies, such as Developed economies, there is not convergence among all of the economies. So, Japan, France, and the US all vary around a single value, but Africa remains mired in poverty, seemingly unaffected by worldwide economic growth. The existing Solow Growth Model could not explain this, except to trivially note the African economies had lower productivity, a parameter in the Solow Growth Model. The Romer model has the form

Y=F(x(i),k(i),K)

and x(i) is the labor of an individual, k(i) a firm's capital (assume people are also firms). K=sum(k(i)), reflecting the idea that bigger economies have more knowledge, and thus, greater productivity. F is increasing in all its arguments. The key technical point he makes is to assume Y is a concave function of k(i) and x(i), which is necessary for an equilibrium to exist, yet because F is increasing in K, you have increasing returns to scale in aggregate. Thus, a competitive equilibrium exists even with increasing returns to scale, because their individual effect on total output K is insignificant (otherwise, with increasing returns to scale, everyone soon chooses infinity to maximize their production/utility).

Most interestingly you get multiple equilibria, in that if you can coordinate everyone to invest a lot, growth is higher than otherwise. This highlights the potential for good institutions to incent greater growth, say by offering more secure property rights, or intellectual property laws. Prosperity becomes a coordination problem, seemingly soluble by abstruse mathematics.

This is the cause of great joy among economists because it allows for lots of modelling: you can prove an equilibrium exists in the infinite horizon case using Hamiltonians, which have proved very useful in physics (the gold standard for science). The end result of this is Bob Lucas's Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics, a book with a lot of math but not much insight (ever since John Nash successfully used a fixed point theorem to prove his eponymous equilibrium, economists have been eager to apply fixed point theorems to other problems, without much success).

The new growth theory tries to explain productivity 'endogenously', as opposed to Solow's exogenous treatment. Yet what is Romer's take away, when translated into words? First, he repeats again and again that higher productivity leads to higher productivity. But that can't be right, in the sense that growth rates of developed countries are not increasing over the past 100 years. I think what he means is that developed countries keep growing, while undeveloped ones don't, do to their 'bad equilibrium'. So we are back to, why does the US have the good one and not Haiti?

Then Romer seems really happy about noticing that productivity is not merely more stuff, but stuff differently arranged. He notes there's a machine that using carbon, oxygen, hydrogen and a few other atoms that is smaller than a car, renews itself, fixes itself, and creates valuable output. What is it? A cow! See, all we have to do is arrange atoms into cow-like things, and the future of robot maids, jetpacks, and holodecks will finally arrive. I don't see this kind of insight rising above the fantasies of your average comic book reader.

In Romer's Fora.tv talk, he talks about theses issues, and highlights that a growing economy has 4 major pieces:

1) competition
2) entry
3) emulation
4) exit (loser firms are reallocated to winner firms)

He gets excited by the idea that many countries could be like Hong Kong in the pre-Chinese era, taking Britain's superior laws, customs, and technology. Yet, even in the US, things like competition, entry, and exit are heavily legislated against by entrenched interests. Sure, Haiti or Paraguay could allow in foreigners to set up franchises, but they don't, because that seems to many as exploitation, and has the stench of racism. So we are back to the old ideas about international trade, the distribution of wealth, and especially the distribution of wealth among various ethnicities. A ruling clique would keep their people poor rather than turn over, say, Petrobras to Exxon.

Japan in 1854 seems the best model for an economy that emulated existing technology, where the Japanese noted their technical deficiency after being defeated by the US Navy and then adopted Western technology without having the Westerners actually own anything. So the question is why did Japan do this, but not the hundred or so other undeveloped countries? Romer's big idea seems best addressed by much less mathematical analysis; his model is sterile when applied to the real world.

Romer's asking the right questions, but as Michele Boldrin noted in Against Intellectual Monopoly, the question about the value of various forms of patents is an empirical one, not deducible from theory. Clearly Romer's work motivated Kling and Schultz's chapter 2, which highlights the nature of our industrial revolution, which is truly remarkable. But to think that Romer's 'economic growth theory' has anything really to add, I haven't seen it.

Sunday, November 29, 2009

Kling and Schultz on Financial Intermediation

I read an interesting book this weekend by Nick Schultz and Arnold Kling: From Poverty to Prosperity. It's a nice exposition of how life has changed over the past 100 years (mainly for the good), interviews with top economists, and provides food for thought on many issues.

In the last section of the book, however, I found their general description of finance to have a misleading emphasis. There was an exposition where assets have risk characteristics that are obscured as they are passed up a food chain, until finally there is greater liquidity, but less information available. Risk is transferred, but because of the lack of transparency, it actually increases.

Clearly, there is transferral of risk in finance, but I think this is not the essence of finance. Finance is intermediation, taking money from savers and giving to people who want to use that money. They, in turn, promise to pay it back. The process generates prices that act as signals to inform those borrowers and savers how best to borrow or save.

Yet, fundamentally, much finance can be considered one of five forms: marketmaking, clearing, originating, servicing, and warehousing. These specializations make for different focus by various firms, so that things important to one set of financial institutions are often irrelevant for another, and 'risk' means different things to different parties, because the risk they retain have different characteristics.

Investment banks, NYSE members, and venture capitalists, often make markets for those wishing to buy or sell. If they merely help connect two parties, like Match.com, they are brokers. If they have an inventory, like Nevada's Bunny Ranch, they are dealers. This activity is primarily about pricing. Risks are mainly about not having a correct hedge.

Clearing transactions such as checks or sales of stocks, is a valuable service, because one needs to know funds actually get from one party to another. For example, it an escrow account, both parties are sure to get their interests prior to losing control of what they are exchanging. Risks are operational, due to fraud or incorrect documentation.

Lenders originate loans or investments via their connections or brand name. This gives money to those who want to buy houses, set up a company, or finance their receivables. It involves marketing, designing products with attractive features, and doing the initial credit evaluation of the borrower and collateral check (underwriting).Risks here involve making 'innovations' to the product that are material, while assuming they are not. As it takes several months for a bad loan to reveal itself, this is why banking is very different than market making, one should have seen several lending cycles to appreciate the importance of various traditions.

Lenders also service these loans, monitoring the ongoing health of the borrower, the collateral, whether he is paying interest, etc. Risk here is operational, in that one must be able to monitor payments, and actually repossess the collateral.

These investments are then finally warehoused as 'assets'. Presumably, idiosyncratic risks are no longer relevant, and so one is left with various exposures to systematic risks: credit cards, housing, banking in general, etc. The ultimate risks due to broad covariance with 'the market', of course, do not disappear, which is the basis of portfolio theory, that only these risks are 'priced' in the sense that one expects a premium for their discomfort. Alas, that theory fails empirically, in that no one has been able to find a general covariance that explains the relative returns of assets (see my book, Finding Alpha).

These 5 attributes of finance are complements, and so many firms have overlapping functions. Yet, some specialize, and so investment companies often are merely in the process of warehousing, buying equities or debt and bundling them into portfolios. As the ultimate owners, these warehousers hold most of the value of the investment, yet, some of the value must be apportioned to each, necessary part of the financial process, and so servicers, clearing firms, market makers, and originators receive some of the money, often a fixed transaction cost. It is wise to keep originators honest, and servicers diligent, by having them retain some of the residual risk of any investment.

This does not contradict the idea of financial intermediation as risk transfer, yet it highlights the fact that the basic risks that are kept away from the warehousing are generally those that are presumed to disappear. A good originator, or servicer, monitors and manages his task so that an investor can assume his asset has a certain expected return and variance and covariance.

In the housing crisis, the complexity of the CDOs and derivatives was incidental to the assumption that housing prices across the country, would suffer only negligible year-over-year declines. Everyone made this mistake: greedy bankers, clueless academics, regulators, even Robert Shiller in 2005 could only muster up the observation that the increase in housing prices was probably not going to continue, and further, some cities might experience declines. Add to that the power of diversification, and complexity grows. Unfortunately, when the AAA-rated Mortgage backed securities defaulted, the question arose as to what was the essence of the 'mistake': housing? AAA ratings? Rating agencies? Securitization? Bankers? The Fed? All AAA rated debt became suspect, and raising this rate across the board made many projects unsustainable.

So, I don't think it was 'too much opacity' that was the essence of our recent problem. Rather, it was a bad assumption, one that very few people mentioned prior to 2007 (see Stan Liebowitz). That was not a risk hidden via the other participants in the intermediation process, rather, the many people who witnessed the degradation in lending standards for homebuying thought they were doing something morally right and empirically innocuous, not worth highlighting.

testequation



Friday, November 27, 2009

The Advisor Weblog

The Advisor Weblog


Hourly perspective for majors’

Posted: 27 Nov 2009 06:46 AM PST

Stocks are regaining the upside strongly in America, still far from past Wednesday close, yet pushing dollar and yen lower, yet gold remains under $1160,  not letting the rally extend too much. Here is the hourly perspective for majors:

http://www.fxstreet.com/technical/analysis-reports/currency-majors-technical-perspective/2009-11-27.v02.html


Best pair to trade now:AUD/USD

Posted: 27 Nov 2009 05:55 AM PST

GBP/USD technical points

Posted: 27 Nov 2009 05:06 AM PST

Gbp/Usd has fell also at the beginning of Asia, after rumours U.K. will downgrade the GDP for next year strongly, breaking under past week low of 1.6460 and reached the strong zone just above 1.6250, as we comment yesterday at the Wrap up webinar. Now with stocks in positive territory in Europe, pair approaches to that 1.6460 resistance level, supported by indicators, exhausted to the downside in the 4 hours charts; above that level, 1.6520 and 1.6560 are next resistances today,  while from current 1.6400 area, supports lie at 1.6360 area, 1.6310 and mentioned 1.6250 area.

 


Aud/Usd broke first key support

Posted: 27 Nov 2009 04:48 AM PST

As I always told you, Australian dollar being a commodity related currency, usually leads the way.As we comment yesterday at the Live Daily Wrap Up, opening under daily ascendant trend line, was a strong bearish signal, that should target the strong 0.8940 zone, where we have the monthly Fibo, and several lows and bounces since pair overcome the level. As you can see in this chart, pair reached that level, and bounced again to the upside, yet remains close to it, holding around 0.9000. With indicators overextended to the downside, yet still bearish, confirmations under today’s low of 0.8916 should trigger further selling in the pair. Next supports come at 0.8855 area, also quiet strong, and under it 0.8800 level. To the upside, resistances today lie at 0.9035, 0.9080, and 0.9120.

 


EUR/USD testing strong support zone

Posted: 27 Nov 2009 04:10 AM PST

Euro fall halted at a very interesting point: we have not only the daily ascendant trend line coming form early March this year, but also the previous base of the range (range before the break higher) barely above 1.4800/10. Seems a tough area for me really, and won’t be easy to see a break lower. Yet, any confirmation there, supported by more falls in stocks and gold, should send the pair quickly lower, with next supports at 1.4760 area, followed by 1.4710. Resistances today, lie at 1.4930, 1.4970 y 1.5010.

Fighting the 1.4900 area, 4 hours charts remain bearish, and only 200 EMA remains under current price, close to the trend line mentioned above. However, price action will remain as always, highly attached to gold and stocks. Keep an eye there, as last Asian session, news where talking about another “black Friday” and we know, sentiment could move the market big.

 


Majors’ sentiment for today

Posted: 27 Nov 2009 03:53 AM PST

Here is majors’ sentiment for today:

Eur/Usd:  Bearish

Gbp/Usd: Bearish

Usd/Chf: Slightly Bullish

Usd/Jpy: Bearish

Eur/Gbp: Bullish


Starting the day

Posted: 27 Nov 2009 03:50 AM PST

Hi everyone, welcome back! I won’t extend the introduction today, as we have plenty to look at charts. Few minutes before Asia opened, and mostly i believe due to speculation: Yen selling started and accelerate even before Nikkei opening, generating further risk aversion. Gold is down, yet far from the 1137 low, stocks in  Europe are negative but regaining ground quickly and so do American futures. Yet dollar and yen remain strong, so let’s see how close we are to key technical points.

No more news for today, but a minor report in Canada.

Have a great trading day!