There are several reasons for protectionism (can be evaluative when pros and cons are discussed):
- assist domestic producers (and thus "save" jobs and ensure votes?)
- protect an infant industry
- combat dumping and low cost labor from abroad
- make money for the government
- avoid over reliance on too few industries
- have important products in case of emergency
- fix balance of payments deficit
- protect domestic consumers against dangerous imports
- assist domestic producers (and thus "save" jobs and ensure votes?)
- protect an infant industry
- combat dumping and low cost labor from abroad
- make money for the government
- avoid over reliance on too few industries
- have important products in case of emergency
- fix balance of payments deficit
- protect domestic consumers against dangerous imports
Tariff:
Graph Analysis:
If this country (Domestic) were closed to trade, equilibrium would occur at a price of Pe and a quantity of Qe for corn. However, when the country opens itself to uninhibited free trade, the country benefits from a global supply of corn, much of which is produced at a lower cost (and thus a lower price) from foreign producers. In this situation, the domestic producers produce 0Q1 corn and foreign produces make the rest, Q1Q2. Both groups of producers accept a price of Pworld, and by multiplying price by quantity, we see domestic producers earn box a and foreign producers earn b, c, d and e.
Let's now assume the domestic government imposes a tariff on foreign corn to protect its own producers. The supply curve Sworld shifts up the value of the tariff to Sworld+Tariff and the new price is Pworld+Tariff. When this occurs, moving up along the domestic supply curve, we observe domestic producers produce 0Q3. Because these firms are more inefficient than the foreign producers who can produce more cheaply, we identify box h as a loss in world efficiency. Moreover, we also have to move backwads up along the demand curve because the price has changed, showing us that foreign producers produce Q3Q4 since Q4Q2 is now lost. This represents a loss of consumer surplus (see relevant post) and is labeled k. As for earnings, the domestic producers now make a, b, f, g, h and foreign producers make c, d. The domestic government receives i, j as tariff (tax) revenue from the foreign producers. The combination of losses in world efficiency and consumer surplus together are called a deadweight loss of welfare because they make some people worse off.
Subsidy:
Graph Analysis:
If this country (Domestic) were closed to trade, equilibrium would occur at a price of Pe and a quantity of Qe for barley. However, when the country opens itself to uninhibited free trade, the country benefits from a global supply of barley, much of which is produced at a lower cost (and thus a lower price) from foreign producers. In this situation, the domestic producers produce 0Q1 barley and foreign produces make the rest, Q1Q2. Both groups of producers accept a price of Pworld, and by multiplying price by quantity, we see domestic producers earn box a and foreign producers earn b, c, d.
Let's then assume the domestic government assists its producers by given them a subsidy (financial aid to domestic producers of g/s making production cheaper). The supply curve Sdomestic shifts out the value of the subsidy to Sdomestic+Subsidy. Domestic firms receive the new price Pworld+Subsidy. When this occurs, moving up along the domestic supply curve, we observe domestic producers produce 0Q3. The foreign producers supply the rest, Q3Q2 and earn c, d. Because the domestic firms are more inefficient than the foreign producers since they require a higher price to produce Q1Q3, we identify box g as a loss in world efficiency (and thus deadweight loss in welfare). The domestic producers now make a, b, e, f, g and foreign producers make c, d.
Quota:
Graph Analysis:
If this country (Domestic) were closed to trade, equilibrium would occur at a price of Pe and a quantity of Qe for sorghum. However, when the country opens itself to uninhibited free trade, the country benefits from a global supply of sorghum, much of which is produced at a lower cost (and thus a lower price) from foreign producers. In this situation, the domestic producers produce 0Q1 of sorghum and foreign produces make the rest, Q1Q2. Both groups of producers accept a price of Pworld, and by multiplying price by quantity, we see domestic producers earn box a and foreign producers earn b, c, d and e.
Let's then assume the domestic government imposes a quota (a limit on foreign g/s) on foreign sorghum to benefit its own producers. The supply curve Sdomestic shifts out to assume production after the quota is reached to Sdomestic+Quota. When this occurs, moving up along the domestic supply curve, we observe domestic producers produce 0Q1, foreign producers produce Q1Q3 (the value of the quota) and domestic producers pick up the rest, Q3Q4. Because these firms are more inefficient than the foreign producers who can produce more cheaply, we identify box j as a loss in world efficiency. We move up backwards along the demand curve because the price has changed to Pw+Quota, showing us that domestic producers stop at Q4 since Q4Q2 is now lost. This represents a loss of consumer surplus and is labeled k. As for earnings, the domestic producers now make a, f, c, i j and foreign producers make b, g, h. Like a tariff, the combination of losses in world efficiency and consumer surplus together are called a deadweight loss of welfare because they make some people worse off.
Graph Analysis:
If this country (Domestic) were closed to trade, equilibrium would occur at a price of Pe and a quantity of Qe for corn. However, when the country opens itself to uninhibited free trade, the country benefits from a global supply of corn, much of which is produced at a lower cost (and thus a lower price) from foreign producers. In this situation, the domestic producers produce 0Q1 corn and foreign produces make the rest, Q1Q2. Both groups of producers accept a price of Pworld, and by multiplying price by quantity, we see domestic producers earn box a and foreign producers earn b, c, d and e.
Let's now assume the domestic government imposes a tariff on foreign corn to protect its own producers. The supply curve Sworld shifts up the value of the tariff to Sworld+Tariff and the new price is Pworld+Tariff. When this occurs, moving up along the domestic supply curve, we observe domestic producers produce 0Q3. Because these firms are more inefficient than the foreign producers who can produce more cheaply, we identify box h as a loss in world efficiency. Moreover, we also have to move backwads up along the demand curve because the price has changed, showing us that foreign producers produce Q3Q4 since Q4Q2 is now lost. This represents a loss of consumer surplus (see relevant post) and is labeled k. As for earnings, the domestic producers now make a, b, f, g, h and foreign producers make c, d. The domestic government receives i, j as tariff (tax) revenue from the foreign producers. The combination of losses in world efficiency and consumer surplus together are called a deadweight loss of welfare because they make some people worse off.
Subsidy:
Graph Analysis:
If this country (Domestic) were closed to trade, equilibrium would occur at a price of Pe and a quantity of Qe for barley. However, when the country opens itself to uninhibited free trade, the country benefits from a global supply of barley, much of which is produced at a lower cost (and thus a lower price) from foreign producers. In this situation, the domestic producers produce 0Q1 barley and foreign produces make the rest, Q1Q2. Both groups of producers accept a price of Pworld, and by multiplying price by quantity, we see domestic producers earn box a and foreign producers earn b, c, d.
Let's then assume the domestic government assists its producers by given them a subsidy (financial aid to domestic producers of g/s making production cheaper). The supply curve Sdomestic shifts out the value of the subsidy to Sdomestic+Subsidy. Domestic firms receive the new price Pworld+Subsidy. When this occurs, moving up along the domestic supply curve, we observe domestic producers produce 0Q3. The foreign producers supply the rest, Q3Q2 and earn c, d. Because the domestic firms are more inefficient than the foreign producers since they require a higher price to produce Q1Q3, we identify box g as a loss in world efficiency (and thus deadweight loss in welfare). The domestic producers now make a, b, e, f, g and foreign producers make c, d.
Quota:
Graph Analysis:
If this country (Domestic) were closed to trade, equilibrium would occur at a price of Pe and a quantity of Qe for sorghum. However, when the country opens itself to uninhibited free trade, the country benefits from a global supply of sorghum, much of which is produced at a lower cost (and thus a lower price) from foreign producers. In this situation, the domestic producers produce 0Q1 of sorghum and foreign produces make the rest, Q1Q2. Both groups of producers accept a price of Pworld, and by multiplying price by quantity, we see domestic producers earn box a and foreign producers earn b, c, d and e.
Let's then assume the domestic government imposes a quota (a limit on foreign g/s) on foreign sorghum to benefit its own producers. The supply curve Sdomestic shifts out to assume production after the quota is reached to Sdomestic+Quota. When this occurs, moving up along the domestic supply curve, we observe domestic producers produce 0Q1, foreign producers produce Q1Q3 (the value of the quota) and domestic producers pick up the rest, Q3Q4. Because these firms are more inefficient than the foreign producers who can produce more cheaply, we identify box j as a loss in world efficiency. We move up backwards along the demand curve because the price has changed to Pw+Quota, showing us that domestic producers stop at Q4 since Q4Q2 is now lost. This represents a loss of consumer surplus and is labeled k. As for earnings, the domestic producers now make a, f, c, i j and foreign producers make b, g, h. Like a tariff, the combination of losses in world efficiency and consumer surplus together are called a deadweight loss of welfare because they make some people worse off.
No comments:
Post a Comment