To put it technically, the “new Keynesian IS [investment-savings] curve” is an asset pricing equation, one of a form very close to those exposed as empirically deficient by Hansen and Singleton. Efforts to repair the asset pricing theory are part and parcel of the important project of building an econometric model suitable for providing quantitative guidance to monetary and fiscal policymakers.I don't think this approach will work because I don't think standard asset pricing theory is near correct, and I'm not a fan of Keynesian macro models either. But here's an asset class that highlights why macro is in such a futz, why such different macro views can be held simultaneous by smart researchers: you can't reject their different priors.
Interest rates are probably the oldest and most liquid prices we have, and there are several facts associated with the basic risk-free yield curve:
- The real term structure is fairly flat, but rises and peaks at around a 3-year maturity
- Real rates are much more variable at the short than long end of the curve.
- The nominal yield curve was flat prior to abandoning the gold standard in the 1930s
- Inflation expectations explain the majority of nominal rate fluctuations
- Interest rates have been pretty stationary over the past 100 years.
US Interest Rates and Inflation: 1953-11
As bond returns are a function of their current yield, and the price appreciation from changes in market rates, the rising interest rate environment had low bond returns, the falling had rising ones. This leaves a tale of two regimes, and it isn’t clear whether the low real returns by maturity prior to 1980, and subsequent reversal subsequently, was an ‘expected’ return, or both period were unexpected.
Total Return Regimes to US Treasury Yield Curve: 1954-2011
Economists were just as surprised by the movements in yields over the past 40 years as anyone. I worked in a bank economics department from 1987-9, and can tell you we had no clue we were in a period of secular interest rate reduction, and that those same economists lamented their poor forecasts throughout the 1960’s and 70’s. In the 1990’s, 10-year inflation-indexed yields average about 3.5% in te UK, and exceeded 4% in the US around2000, and declined until a spike in 2008, and currently (2011) are below 1%. These movements are, in the words of Campbell, Shiller, and Vaciera (2009, Understanding Inflation-Indexed Bond Markets), a puzzle.
Keynes’s (1930, Treatise on Money) argued that the yield curve should rise due to a risk premium, Modigliani and Sutch (1966, Innovations in Interest Rate Policy) argue that there’s a habitat preference for interest rate investors, so that some prefer longer bonds, but most shorter durations. With the development of the stochastic discount rate factor, risk premium were supposed to be a function of covariances.
To test the yield curve then, we can look and see if we can explain the pattern across maturities or time, of the real return (the nominal return being trivially higher in higher inflation environments). The standard covariance factors are consumption, and the stock market. Consider the following 'betas' with the S&P500 and Real Consumption Growth range from -0.1 to 0.1, with an average of 0.05, depending on what periods (53-80 vs. 81-11), time horizon (daily vs. 60 month investment horizons), real vs. nominal returns, whether we are regressing against consumption vs. S&P500 returns. The point is, the data here are too noisy to confidently say that short, or long term Treasuries are 'risky': there's always a different view that says something different.
Looking at this over time perhaps shows the problem more clearly:
10 year US Treasury Slope with S&P500 vs. 10 year Total Return
Slope from rolling 85 month monthly returnsThe lower returning early period, and the higher returning later period, do not show a clear distinction in the bond's S&P500 factor loading, and so it is with all the various permutations of these data.
The bottom line is that inflationary periods have lower bond returns than disinflationary periods, though it is not clear whether these are expected, and thus true risk premium. There is no obvious risk premium explanation of the 'default free' spectrum of bonds across maturities or time, and any statistical analysis that purports to say it all makes complete sense is clearly torturing the data (eg, see Bansal's 'long run risks' model that adds a bunch of parameters to explain more datapoints).
This is especially relevant to macroeconomics because in the standard New Keynesian models, a representative agent’s Euler equation that links a one-period real interest rate to the consumption growth rate is the IS curve central to the policy transmission mechanism. A long list of empirical failures come from applying the stochastic discount factor implied by that Euler equation. Until someone succeeds in getting some kind of consumption-based asset pricing model that works well, the New Keynesian IS curve is empirically vacuous.
No comments:
Post a Comment